Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

Search representations

Results for Bidwells search

New search New search

Comment

Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

S/DS: Development strategy

Representation ID: 60243

Received: 10/12/2021

Respondent: Bidwells

Representation Summary:

We support the broad development strategy for the Plan.

Full text:

We support the broad development strategy for the Plan.

Comment

Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

S/JH: New jobs and homes

Representation ID: 60244

Received: 10/12/2021

Respondent: Bidwells

Representation Summary:

In terms of recommendations, it is clear that considerable more analysis is required to determine the most appropriate level of employment need in the context of the unique life science cluster in Greater Cambridge, which will in turn determine the housing need.
This work cannot reasonably progress until the 2021 Census is published in early 2022 and much of the data post-2011, on which the GCLP first proposals is based, is
revised. In the meantime however, the GCSPT could consider the realistic capacity for development within its boundaries – what could be achievable irrespective of need, based on the environmental and social constraints of the area. This work will be essential to determining if any unmet housing and/or employment needs exist for the purposes of the Duty to Cooperate, determining the level of employment and housing need that is actually deliverable, and convincing future government planning
inspector(s) that the GCLP has been positively planned in the context of the significant weight the NPPF places on the need to support economic growth and productivity.

Full text:

Greater Cambridge Employment and Housing Need
1 Introduction
1.1 This report has been prepared by Bidwells LLP, to support representations on the first proposals for the Greater Cambridge Local Plan (GCLP). The report explores the evidence on housing and employment need produced by the Greater Cambridge Shared Planning Team (GCSPT) that are preparing the GCLP for Cambridge City Council (CCC) and South Cambridgeshire District Council (SCDC).
1.2 The GCLP first proposals suggest requirements of 44,400 homes and 58,500 new jobs between 2020 and 2041. Accommodation for gypsies, travellers and travelling show people sites will be proposed but numbers are still to be confirmed.
1.3 The objective assessment of housing and employment need is a requirement of the National Planning Policy Framework (NPPF) and should adhere to the accompanying Planning Practice Guidance (PPG)
1.4 NPPF paragraph 8 explains that to achieve sustainable development, the planning system has three interdependent objectives:
“a) an economic objective – to help build a strong, responsive and competitive economy, by ensuring that sufficient land of the right types is available in the right places and at the right time to support growth, innovation and improved productivity; and by identifying and coordinating the provision of infrastructure;
b) a social objective – to support strong, vibrant and healthy communities, by ensuring that a sufficient number and range of homes can be provided to meet the needs of present and future generations; and by fostering well-designed, beautiful and safe places, with accessible services and open spaces that reflect current and
1.5 NPPF paragraph 11 then explains how the presumption in favour of sustainable
development functions for plan-making:
“a) all plans should promote a sustainable pattern of development that seeks to: meet the development needs of their area; align growth and infrastructure; improve the environment; mitigate climate change (including by making effective use of land in urban areas) and adapt to its effects;
b) strategic policies should, as a minimum, provide for objectively assessed needs for housing and other uses, as well as any needs that cannot be met within neighbouring areas, unless:
i. the application of policies in this Framework that protect areas or assets of
particular importance provides a strong reason for restricting the overall scale,
type or distribution of development in the plan area; or
ii. any adverse impacts of doing so would significantly and demonstrably outweigh the benefits, when assessed against the policies in this Framework taken as a whole.”
1.6 It is within this context that the GCSPT prepared or commissioned the following:
● The Employment Land and Economic Development Evidence Study (ELEDES)
● The Housing and Employment Relationships (HER) report
● The Development Strategy Topic Paper
● The Sustainability Appraisal (SA)
1.7 These reports are considered in the following three chapters with Chapter 5 providing conclusions and recommendations.
2 Employment Need
2.1 As set out in the previous chapter, the NPPF's economic objective set out in paragraph 8 is to:
"help build a strong, responsive and competitive economy, by ensuring that sufficient
land of the right types is available in the right places and at the right time to support
growth, innovation and improved productivity; and by identifying and coordinating the
provision of infrastructure;"
2.2 This should be read in the context of NPPF paragraph 16, which highlights that plans should be prepared positively, in a way that is aspirational but deliverable. NPPF paragraph 35 is also relevant, which makes clear that plans are 'sound' if they are positively prepared - providing a strategy which, as a minimum, seeks to meet the areas objectively assessed needs.
2.3 Chapter Six of the NPPF then sets out specific economic principles with paragraph 81 stating that:
"Planning policies and decisions should help create the conditions in which businesses can invest, expand and adapt. Significant weight should be placed on the need to support economic growth and productivity, taking into account both local business needs and wider opportunities for development. The approach taken should allow each area to build on its strengths, counter any weaknesses and address the challenges of the future. This is particularly important where Britain can be a global leader in driving innovation, and in areas with high levels of productivity, which should be able to capitalise on their performance and potential."
2.4 The Government sees Cambridge’s life sciences cluster as a significant unique selling point for UK PLC when seeking trade partners globally, with UK Trade & Investment (UKTI, now part of the Department for International Trade) committing to help in securing inward investment as part of the 2014 Growth Deal. The importance of its success for the national economy post-Brexit and Covid-19 should not be underestimated. Indeed, the £2.9 billion it contributes to the UK economy was highlighted in the recent consultation on the Oxford-Cambridge Arc Spatial Framework.
2.5 NPPF paragraph 82 continues by making clear that planning policies should:
“a) set out a clear economic vision and strategy which positively and proactively encourages sustainable economic growth, having regard to Local Industrial Strategies and other local policies for economic development and regeneration;
b) set criteria, or identify strategic sites, for local and inward investment to match the strategy and to meet anticipated needs over the plan period;
c) seek to address potential barriers to investment, such as inadequate infrastructure, services or housing, or a poor environment; and
d) be flexible enough to accommodate needs not anticipated in the plan, allow for new and flexible working practices (such as live-work accommodation), and to enable a rapid response to changes in economic circumstances.”
2.6 Finally, NPPF paragraph 83 states that:
“Planning policies and decisions should recognise and address the specific locational requirements of different sectors. This includes making provision for clusters or networks of knowledge and data-driven, creative or high technology industries; and for storage and distribution operations at a variety of scales and in suitably accessible locations.”
2.7 What is very clear from the NPPF therefore is the importance of enabling aspirational sustainable economic growth, particularly in areas that benefit from specific clusters that are important to the UK economy and its share in the global economy. It is also clear that when determining the scale of economic growth a plan should seek to target, it should only be limited by what can reasonably be delivered, without constraint. Environmental or social constraints might be applied later in order to achieve a pattern of sustainable development, but the starting point for formulating policy should be deliverable, objectively assessed, economic growth.
2.8 The PPG is relatively limited on how the objectively assessed employment need should be determined. At paragraph 2a-027 it suggests that following sources of data:
• “sectoral and employment forecasts and projections which take account of likely
changes in skills needed (labour demand)
• demographically derived assessments of current and future local labour supply (labour supply techniques)
• analysis based on the past take-up of employment land and property and/or future property market requirements
• consultation with relevant organisations, studies of business trends, an understanding of innovative and changing business models, particularly those which make use of online platforms to respond to consumer demand and monitoring of business, economic and employment statistics.”
2.9 The paragraph ends by stating that:
“Authorities will need to take account of longer term economic cycles in assessing this data, and consider and plan for the implications of alternative economic scenarios.”
2.10 For the GCLP, employment need is calculated within the ELEDES.
2.11 The ELEDES recognises that forecasting employment is complicated, mostly due to the rapid changes seen in employment growth over the last decade compared to the decade before. As a result, there are several estimates of current employment across Greater Cambridge that cannot at this time be rationalised to form a single base to which then be used to forecast future employment need.
2.12 When published next year, the 2021 Census will assist in this and will result in much of the data on which the ELEDES is based on, from the 2011 Census onwards, being revised. In many areas these revisions will be minimal but areas that have seen substantial change, such as Greater Cambridge, are likely to see the greatest revisions. It is likely therefore that the ELEDES will require revision before the GCLP is adopted.
2.13 In essence the ELEDES relies heavily on the East of England Forecasting Model (EEFM), deviating from it only for key industrial sectors that the model is known to struggle with, namely the research and development, health and care, and professional services sectors.
2.14 The EEFM was originally designed by Oxford Economics and is currently owned by the East of England Local Government Association (EELGA). The most recent outputs of the model have been prepared by Cambridge Econometrics. These outputs are 2019 based and use the ONS 2016-based Sub National Population Projections (2016SNPP). The 2016SNPP has since been replaced by the 2018SNPP.
2.15 There have been a number of criticisms of the EEFM in recent years, most notably how the model is constrained to the 2016SNPP at the regional level. This means that any economic growth that would need a greater population than that seen in the 2016SNPP is effectively disregarded. In addition, many of the assumptions are fixed at the 2011 Census results, such as in the commuting matrix that determines residence employment, with no provision to modify these where more recent data suggest they are no longer appropriate.
2.16 Care therefore needs to be had in considering the results of the EEFM in a strategic planning context, where the NPPF requires the employment need to be unconstrained and objectively assessed.
2.17 Fundamentally, since the completion of the ELEDES, the EELGA has now decided to discontinue updating the EEFM. While the reasons for this are unclear, the fact that both the original designer, Oxford Economics, and the latest operator, Cambridge Econometrics, both produce economic projections that are not constrained by population, it is likely that it is no longer considered fit for purpose.
2.18 Despite this, this does not mean that the EEFM should be automatically disregarded. It does provide a good indicator of how the economy may develop within the context of the assumptions included in the model. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume as a baseline that employment growth would be 40,100 jobs between 2020 and 2041 as the ELEDES sets out. However, as is recognised, this would mean that those key sectors that the EEFM struggles with would be heavily constrained.
2.19 To remedy this the ELEDES takes these key sectors and considers them separately. It recognises that if historical average growth rates were to be applied, future growth would be exponential. In many cases exponential growth would not matter as the real increase in employment each year would be miniscule. However, based on the rapid growth seen in recent years in these key sectors, exponential growth would quickly become undeliverable. Therefore the ELEDES, quite rightly seeks to ‘dampen down’ this growth to a more realistic level.
2.20 However, what is concerning is that this dampening down is based on the EEFM baseline projection –the very projection that the ELEDES acknowledges fails to adequately address growth in the key sectors in the first place. Furthermore, the ELEDES only sets out two scenarios for this dampening down:
● The Central Growth Scenario (KS2) which is the lower quartile between the EEFM baseline projection and the historic growth rate between 2001 and 2017.
● The Higher Growth Scenario (KS3) which is the mid-point between the EEFM baseline projection and the historic growth rate between 2001 and 2017.
2.21 No consideration appears to have been given to a scenario using the upper quartile.
2.22 Fundamentally there appears to be little analysis of which quartile (which are in themselves arbitrary) might be the most appropriate beyond the assertion that the Greater Cambridge economy is at a peak and over the longer term growth will likely be lower than that seen in the past decade.
2.23 This fails to recognise the unique narrative behind the exceptional growth seen in the past decade.
2.24 The last Cambridgeshire Structure Plan and East of England Regional Spatial Strategy sought to heavily constrain development around Cambridge, in particular by limiting the amount of non-R&D floorspace that could be built. The Green Belt as well acted as a clear brake on development, preventing the expansion of Cambridge.
2.25 It was not until the currently adopted Cambridge City and South Cambridgeshire Local Plans started to be developed that these tight restrictions started to be loosened, in the context of the new NPPF, which promoted economic growth. Even then, many developments were affected by the 2008 recession and investment was hesitant until the plans were finally adopted in 2018. It was therefore only after 2018 that investment truly started to reflect its full potential. In the three short years since then, which have seen the Covid-19 pandemic and the realisation of Brexit, insufficient data is available to determine where in an economic cycle the Greater Cambridge economy might currently be.
2.26 Given that most of the data used in the ELEDES pre-dates 2018, prior to the adoption of the local plans, it is highly unlikely that it represents the peak in the Greater Cambridge economic cycle.
2.27 Assuming therefore that those key sectors that contribute such a significant proportion of the growth in recent years should reflect the lower quartile between the EEFM and historic growth rate is unreasonable. It would suggest that the mid-point or the upper quartile might be more appropriate, perhaps an even higher figure.
2.28 It is also important to not focus entirely on those key sectors. For every person working in those key sectors, there will need to be people working in other essential sectors if the local economy is to function. For example, there is little point in making specific provision for life scientists if provision is not also made for those teaching their children, serving them in the supermarket, or those building their new home.
2.29 The analysis in the ELEDES does not seem to recognise this ‘sticky’ relationship between sectors. If one sector is being uplifted from the EEFM baseline, all other sectors should also be uplifted to some degree to balance the economy.
2.30 At this stage, with the 2021 Census to be published early next year, it is not appropriate to provide an alternative analysis of employment need. However, it is likely that the answer is within Table 10 of the ELEDES. This shows that the lowest projected employment growth is derived from the EEFM at 40,100 jobs while the highest is from the 2011-2017 annual average change at 125,200 jobs.
2.31 This higher figure is likely to be too high, not least because (reflecting the NPPF) it is unlikely to be deliverable. The lowest the GCLP should be planning for is 45,761 jobs, which is linked to the Local Housing Need Standard Method (LHNSM), rather than the EEFM 40,100 jobs.
2.32 Realistically, employment need is likely to be the average between the 2001-2017 annual average change and 2011-2017 annual average change, 90,250 jobs. This closely reflects the CPEIR proxy result of 92,100 jobs. This would seem to best fit the requirements of the NPPF by reflecting an unconstrained view of employment growth while recognising what is realistically deliverable.
3 Housing Need
3.1 As set out in chapter one, the NPPF's social objective set out in paragraph 8 is to:“support strong, vibrant and healthy communities, by ensuring that a sufficient number and range of homes can be provided to meet the needs of present and future generations; and by fostering well-designed, beautiful and safe places, with accessible services and open spaces that reflect current and future needs and support communities’ health, social and cultural well-being;”
3.2 Housing is central to the NPPF and is referenced more than any other use. As set out in paragraph 60:
“To support the Government’s objective of significantly boosting the supply of homes, it is important that a sufficient amount and variety of land can come forward where it is needed, that the needs of groups with specific housing requirements are addressed and that land with permission is developed without unnecessary delay.”
3.3 To this end, the Government has introduced the Local Housing Need Standard Method (LHNSM) in paragraph 61 of the NPPF to determine the minimum number of homes that strategic planning policies should plan for. However, LHNSM is not the objectively assessed need for housing, which is the minimum amount of housing strategic policies should seek to achieve, as clearly set out in NPPF paragraph 11. It is therefore incumbent on a strategic plan-maker to determine if the objectively assessed need is higher or lower than the LHNSM. If the objectively assessed need is lower than the LHNSM, the LHNSM takes precedence and the objectively assessed need becomes largely irrelevant. If the objectively assessed need is higher than the LHNSM, the OAN takes precedence and the LHNSM becomes entirely irrelevant as it is a simple policy tool.
3.4 Paragraph 2a-010 of the PPG explains the circumstances where the objectively assessed need for housing is likely to be higher than the LHNSM, which does not:“predict the impact that future government policies, changing economic circumstances or other factors might have on demographic behaviour”.
3.5 The paragraph then provides some examples of circumstances where this might be appropriate such as growth strategies, strategic infrastructure improvements or unmet needs from neighbouring authority (the latter is not relevant in this case). The paragraph then notes that there might be other evidence to suggest significantly greater levels of housing need, such as Strategic Housing Market Assessments (SHMAs).
3.6 In the case of Greater Cambridge, the ELEDES clearly sets out the employment need would require more housing than suggested by the LHNSM. Therefore the LHNSM is no longer relevant and no further consideration is given to it in this report.
3.7 The HER report takes the two employment need scenarios set out in the ELEDES, as discussed in the previous chapter, and converts the number of jobs into homes.
3.8 To do this the HER needs to first determine the baseline resident population. In
Cambridge, this has always been an issue given its substantial student population and yet the HER analysis seems to misunderstand this. While the report does identify that the differences between official population estimates and the much higher estimates for the patient register are most likely due to students, it dismisses the patient register on the basis that too few dwellings have been delivered since 2011 to accommodate that population rise.
3.9 There are two issues with this. First, using dwellings as the measure ignores student housing entirely, which will have supported a considerable population. Second, where students are occupying market housing, they tend to do so at far greater densities (people per household) than families.
3.10 In terms of the first point, the Housing Land Supply report identifies that 1,112 dwellings were completed in Cambridge in 2017/18 and 868 dwellings in 2018/19. However the Housing Delivery Test (HDT) results suggests that the number of homes delivered, which includes communal establishments, was 1,145 and 1,098 respectively. This alone suggests 13% more homes than dwellings alone.
3.11 Rather than just blending the two sources of population data, it would be better to provide scenarios considering the implications of using the official estimates, the patient register and different blends of the two. This would allow the reader to understand the sensitivities involved.
3.12 Other economic variables such as unemployment rates, economic activity rates and double-jobbing are considered appropriate. The one exception however is the
commuting ratio applied.
3.13 It is welcome that the GCSLT have selected the 1:1 commuting scenario as the housing requirement to pursue. However, it is concerning that this 1:1 only relates to jobs in excess of those supported by housing equivalent to the LHNSM result using the 2011 Census ratio. As discussed above, the LHNSM is purely a policy tool for determining the minimum number of homes LPAs should seek to plan for. Its inaccuracies are well documented and there is no valid reason to include it in any form in a more comprehensive analysis of housing need.
3.14 As such, the modelling should be revised to consider the implications of a 1:1 commuting scenario on all jobs to be delivered by the GCLP. In addition, it would be appropriate to consider the implications of a further uplift in housing to remedy the rise in in-commuting as a result of the adopted local plans failing to provide sufficient housing for the actual growth in employment. This has led to housing pressures in surrounding areas that were not planned for and would perpetuate a pattern of unsustainable commuting unless addressed.
3.15 As discussed in the Development Strategy Topic Paper, the actual level of 44,400 homes pursued in the GCLP first proposals consultation is linked entirely to the selected employment need. If the employment need was deemed to be higher, the housing need would be higher too. This is entirely appropriate but highlights how fundamental it is to ensure the correct employment need is selected to avoid a repeat of the increased in-commuting seen as a result of proposals largely facilitated by the currently adopted local plans.
3.16 However, there also appears to be confusion by what is actually meant by ‘homes’ (referred to in the Topic Paper and GCLP first proposals) and ‘dwellings’ (refereed to in the HER). As discussed above, the two are not the same.
3.17 In determining the household formation rates, the HER would have first discounted an amount of the population each year that would live in communal establishments such
as student accommodation and care homes. For most age groups this is a fixed number of people living in communal establishments with the exception of those aged 75+ where the percentage of the population aged 75+ that lived in communal establishments is used. In both circumstances the data is taken from the 2011 Census and is assumed to remain fixed up until the base date of the projection (in this case 2020) through to the end of the projection.
3.18 In the case of the HER, it is clear that a considerable number of homes in communal establishments were delivered in 2017/18 and 2018/19, and it is highly likely that similar numbers were delivered each year since 2011. Therefore the starting assumptions for the base date are likely to be incorrect and this is likely to have influenced the household formation rates used.
3.19 Furthermore, because the number of people of an age that are likely to be students remains fixed, the projections cannot consider any additional need for student accommodation.
3.20 It is complex to model this within the projections and instead this additional growth is usually determined in consultation with the universities to take account of their specific plans for expansion. This doesn’t appear to have happened, which is surprising given that Greater Cambridge has one of the greatest concentrations of students relative to the size of its resident population.
3.21 Consequently, the housing requirement of 44,400 must be dwellings only because it does not include any consideration of communal establishments of any kind.
4 Sustainability Appraisal
4.1 The Sustainability Appraisals are required to incorporate the statutorily required Strategic Environmental Assessments (SEAs) of policies and plans. As part of this, there is a requirement for reasonable alternatives to considered on a like-for-like basis, allowing the reader to compare the environmental effects and wider sustainability issues associated with different development scenarios.
4.2 The quantum of development is but one area that logically should be subject to reasonable alternatives, particularly where the evidence base (both the ELEDES and HER) set out a series of scenarios for the decision maker (in this case the GTSPT) to consider before selecting the most appropriate as a matter of planning judgement. It is surprising therefore that the SA accompanying the GCLP first proposals fails to identify any reasonable alternatives relating to the quantum of development.
4.3 The reasons given for this are self-defeating. Two potential alternative options are considered before being discounted:
“B. Alternative option - Planning for the higher jobs forecast and level of homes associated with it. This alternative has not been assessed as it is not considered to be reasonable. This is because the higher jobs forecast could be possible, but is not the most likely future scenario. As such we do not consider that it represents our objectively assessed need, and would therefore not be a reasonable alternative.
C. Alternative option - Planning for the government’s standard method local housing need figure. This alternative has not been assessed as it is not considered to be reasonable. This is because it would not support the most likely forecast for future jobs. As such, the Councils do not consider that it represents our objectively assessed need, and would therefore not be a reasonable alternative. Failure to reflect that likely level of growth, would lead to increased commuting into the area (with consequent impacts on quality of life, wellbeing and carbon emissions objectives for the plan).”
4.4 It is agreed that Option C would not be reasonable given the overwhelming evidence that both employment and housing need are far greater than yielded from the LHNSM. That is not to say that a lower level of growth than the preferred option (Option A, the 44,400 homes and 58,500 new jobs set out in the first consultation) would be unreasonable and certainly, it would likely be helpful in teasing out the relative sustainability issues related to the quantum of development.
4.5 The justification for discounting Option B however is clearly erroneous. If it was only necessary to assess the “most likely future scenario”, there would be no assessment of alternatives of any kind. This is contrary to the entire purpose of SA and SEA.
4.6 The ELEDES makes clear that, while it concludes that the Central Growth Scenario (58,500 jobs) is the most likely, the Higher Growth Scenario is entirely possible. Indeed, as set out in this report it is entirely plausible and therefore reasonable.
4.7 To withhold the full assessment of Option B alongside Option A effectively blinds the decision maker to the differences in environmental effect and sustainability between them. The decision maker cannot conclude that however less likely Option B might be compared to Option A, whether the possibility of success outweighs or reduces the environmental impact.
4.8 This approach has been noted as a concern during the examination of the Babergh and Mid Suffolk Joint Local Plan13, which has been suspended pending further work by the Councils.
5 Conclusions and Recommendations
5.1 The objective assessments of employment and housing need supporting the GCLP first proposals consultation are substantial. They thoroughly consider the data complexities resulting from the rapid economic growth following the period of restraint demanded by the previous County Structure Plan. The employment need assessment in particular however considers that this rapid growth is unsustainable in the long term, and would likely fall back to an average rate of growth seen in the early 2000s, before proposals in the currently adopted local plans took shape.
5.2 Bidwells believe that this undermines the Cambridge Phenomenon that has been gathering pace since the 1960s, but is only now starting to convert the academic advances in life sciences into commercial success, a result of those local plans adopted in 2018. It suggests that the possibility that growth can be sustained is not worth considering and instead Greater Cambridge should be planning for a level of growth comparable to other areas that do not have a unique life sciences cluster, which contributes £2.9 billion annually to the UK economy.
5.3 This is happening at a time when the Covid-19 pandemic has highlighted the importance of all aspects of life science research, from rapidly developing a vaccine, designing effective equipment for rapidly increasing the number of intensive care beds, through to caring for those suffering the long term effects. It is also happening at a time when, following Brexit, the UK is seeking to determine its place in the global economy, outside of the EU.
5.4 While the UK has a lot to offer, the life science research undertaken in Cambridge, and across the whole Oxford to Cambridge Arc, is one of the most unique and highly valued. Now is not the time to constrain growth simply because it ‘might’ be less than what has been sustained previously.
5.5 Bidwells acknowledge that economic growth must be sustainable and that it would be inappropriate to determine a level of need that is undeliverable, as advocated by the NPPF. It is also acknowledged that it is difficult to determine exactly how much employment need there is in the context of such a vibrant economy. It is unique and therefore the approach to assessing need set out in the PPG is perhaps not the best. Certainly, extra care is needed when considering the veracity of economic models, such as the EEFM, that have consistently downplayed economic growth from key sectors over several iterations in recent years. It might therefore be more appropriate, at least as a reasonable alternative, to reverse the analysis and instead consider the available capacity for growth in the area and determine how this sits with the various economic projections under consideration.
5.6 On the subject of reasonable alternatives, the SA accompanying the GCLP first proposals consultation fails to even consider the potential effects of a higher level of economic growth. This is clearly unreasonable, the evidence base itself highlights the uncertainty as to the level of employment need and identifies methodologies and scenarios that would result in a considerably higher level of employment need than the first proposals suggest.
5.7 Lessons must be learnt from the currently adopted local plans that did not anticipate the rapidity of growth they would facilitate, which would inevitably lead to far greater growth over their full plan periods than was considered in their accompanying SAs. It is this failure to consider the possibility of higher rates of economic growth that has led to the increasing level of commuting into Greater Cambridge each day.
5.8 Finally, in terms of housing need, in the case of Greater Cambridge this is simply a function of facilitating economic growth and determining the acceptable level of commuting. The latter will inevitably be a strategic matter for the purposes of the Duty to Cooperate unless the GCLP can show that it is accommodating its full objectively assessed housing need.
5.9 At this stage, with such considerable uncertainty regarding the level of employment need, it is certainly the case that housing need is far higher than that set out in the first proposals consultation and therefore either more land needs to be allocated for housing or comprehensive discussions should be had with neighbouring authorities about how unmet need should be addressed. To facilitate these discussions, the GCSPT would first need to show that there were no more additional sustainable locations for development within their boundaries, which, given the considerable number of sites that are currently being promoted for development is highly unlikely.
5.10 Again, the SA fails to consider any alternative other than the level of need set out in the GCLP first proposals consultation. Quite clearly, if there is uncertainty about the level of employment need, there is also uncertainty about the level of housing need, and the SA should reflect that. Equally, in its consideration of reasonable alternatives, the SA fails to recognise that the greater in-commuting resulting from a higher employment need would be negated by increased housing. Its reasons for limiting the assessment of reasonable alternatives are self-defeating.
5.11 In terms of recommendations, it is clear that considerable more analysis is required to determine the most appropriate level of employment need in the context of the unique life science cluster in Greater Cambridge, which will in turn determine the housing need. This work cannot reasonably progress until the 2021 Census is published in early 2022 and much of the data post-2011, on which the GCLP first proposals is based, is revised. In the meantime however, the GCSPT could consider the realistic capacity for development within its boundaries – what could be achievable irrespective of need, based on the environmental and social constraints of the area. This work will be essential to determining if any unmet housing and/or employment needs exist for the purposes of the Duty to Cooperate, determining the level of employment and housing need that is actually deliverable, and convincing future government planning inspector(s) that the GCLP has been positively planned in the context of the significant weight the NPPF places on the need to support economic growth and productivity.

Comment

Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

Sustainability Appraisal

Representation ID: 60247

Received: 10/12/2021

Respondent: Bidwells

Representation Summary:

The SA accompanying the GCLP first proposals fails to identify any reasonable alternatives relating to the quantum of development.

Full text:

4 Sustainability Appraisal
4.1 The Sustainability Appraisals are required to incorporate the statutorily required Strategic Environmental Assessments (SEAs) of policies and plans. As part of this, there is a requirement for reasonable alternatives to considered on a like-for-like basis, allowing the reader to compare the environmental effects and wider sustainability issues associated with different development scenarios.
4.2 The quantum of development is but one area that logically should be subject to reasonable alternatives, particularly where the evidence base (both the ELEDES and HER) set out a series of scenarios for the decision maker (in this case the GTSPT) to consider before selecting the most appropriate as a matter of planning judgement. It is surprising therefore that the SA accompanying the GCLP first proposals fails to identify any reasonable alternatives relating to the quantum of development.
4.3 The reasons given for this are self-defeating. Two potential alternative options are considered before being discounted:
“B. Alternative option - Planning for the higher jobs forecast and level of homes associated with it. This alternative has not been assessed as it is not considered to be reasonable. This is because the higher jobs forecast could be possible, but is not the most likely future scenario. As such we do not consider that it represents our objectively assessed need, and would therefore not be a reasonable alternative.
C. Alternative option - Planning for the government’s standard method local housing need figure. This alternative has not been assessed as it is not considered to be reasonable. This is because it would not support the most likely forecast for future jobs. As such, the Councils do not consider that it represents our objectively assessed need, and would therefore not be a reasonable alternative. Failure to reflect that likely level of growth, would lead to increased commuting into the area (with consequent impacts on quality of life, wellbeing and carbon emissions objectives for the plan).”
4.4 It is agreed that Option C would not be reasonable given the overwhelming evidence that both employment and housing need are far greater than yielded from the LHNSM. That is not to say that a lower level of growth than the preferred option (Option A, the 44,400 homes and 58,500 new jobs set out in the first consultation) would be unreasonable and certainly, it would likely be helpful in teasing out the relative sustainability issues related to the quantum of development.
4.5 The justification for discounting Option B however is clearly erroneous. If it was only necessary to assess the “most likely future scenario”, there would be no assessment of alternatives of any kind. This is contrary to the entire purpose of SA and SEA.
4.6 The ELEDES makes clear that, while it concludes that the Central Growth Scenario (58,500 jobs) is the most likely, the Higher Growth Scenario is entirely possible. Indeed, as set out in this report it is entirely plausible and therefore reasonable.
4.7 To withhold the full assessment of Option B alongside Option A effectively blinds the decision maker to the differences in environmental effect and sustainability between them. The decision maker cannot conclude that however less likely Option B might be compared to Option A, whether the possibility of success outweighs or reduces the environmental impact.
4.8 This approach has been noted as a concern during the examination of the Babergh and Mid Suffolk Joint Local Plan13, which has been suspended pending further work by the Councils.

Comment

Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

S/RRA: Allocations in the rest of the rural area

Representation ID: 60675

Received: 13/12/2021

Respondent: Bidwells

Representation Summary:

The Drift, Harston (HELAA site 40535)

Response has been provided through the call for sites form responding to the HELAA assessment.

We hope that the positive locational attributes of this site carry enough weight over rural locations which do not havethe adjoining transport connectivity advantages which results in a sustainable transport location.

Full text:

The Drift, Harston (HELAA site 40535)

Response has been provided through the call for sites form responding to the HELAA assessment.

We hope that the positive locational attributes of this site carry enough weight over rural locations which do not havethe adjoining transport connectivity advantages which results in a sustainable transport location.

Comment

Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

S/RRA: Allocations in the rest of the rural area

Representation ID: 60721

Received: 13/12/2021

Respondent: Bidwells

Representation Summary:

Land adjacent to St Georges Way and Woodcock Close, Impington (HELAA site 40282)

Additional information submitted through the call for sites proforma, which demonstrates the potential of this site and fully assesses the site opportunities and constraints.

Comment

Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

S/RRA: Allocations in the rest of the rural area

Representation ID: 60722

Received: 13/12/2021

Respondent: Bidwells

Representation Summary:

Bedlam Farm, Milton Rd, Impington (HELAA site 40389)

Additional information has been submitted through the call for sites proforma.

We have provided direct responses to the issues to the red flag issues identified.

We hope that the locational attributes and the existing uses at this site show an increased connectivity advantage over other undeveloped sites in more rural locations.

Comment

Greater Cambridge Local Plan Preferred Options

S/RRA: Allocations in the rest of the rural area

Representation ID: 60756

Received: 09/12/2021

Respondent: Bidwells

Representation Summary:

High Street, Longstowe (HELAA site 40387)

Additional information submitted through call for sites proforma to respond to issues raised in HELAA.

Considering the commercial use proposed we do not believe that the distances to the facilities set out in the first responses form are paramount. However the proposed development is situated approximately 2 miles form Bourn which has been identified as a group village.

The aim of policy S/RRA is to support the delivery of a range of smaller sites within the area and support the viability of villages. We believe a mixed sue scheme of this nature meets the requirements of the policy and will significantly enhance the village and benefit its residents for the duration of the local plan.

For instructions on how to use the system and make comments, please see our help guide.